Scenarios of the Polish economy dynamics in 2017-2022 on the Ramsey type model basis

Cover Page

Cite item

Abstract

The article contains a methodology of identification of the dynamic Ramsey model for the Polish economy. It includes two different scenarios of the development of the Polish economy for five years (2017-2022) and the comparison of the forecasts made on their basis. The first scenario is built using the model parameters estimated basing on the data for the period 1991-2016. The second scenario considers a more recent period (2010-2016), which is picked according to a hypothesis that the statistical data of this period describing the labor force dynamics shows its trend more representatively. The method of model identification is based on evaluating the proximity between the calculated and statistical time series of macroeconomic indicators (output, consumption, investment, export, import). The GDP and investments volumes are predicted for the five years’ period and the visualization of the forecasted trend is made for the both identified models.

Full Text

Introduction Effective forecasting of the economy is one of the most urgent scientific, political and social problems. There are several reasons for the negative affect on the accuracy of economic forecasts, in addition to the basic problem of uncertainty. Among the first ones the increased complexity of the economic system and the feedback loop (Shaw, 2017; Clements, Hendry, 2002) are traditionally named. An effective means of decreasing the feedback loop effect is to build several variants of forecast with a graded probability measure. In its turn, the increased complexity led to the failure of traditional theory of economic forecasting (Joutz, 2006). In terms of development of scientific researches in this field this meant moving from linear models and unconditional forecasting to dynamic models, based on time series approximation. The dynamic model of the economy, in which production is defined by the neoclassical production function, and the production factors (labor and capital) are changing due to the given differential equations, was called the Ramsey model in honor of the fundamental work of Frank Plampton Ramsey (Ramsey, 1928), in which the problem of the optimal level of savings in a closed economy was considered. This simplest dynamic model of the economy was used by many scientists in the theoretical studies of the economy, both before and after Ramsey (Moiseev, 1975), Robert Solow's great contribution to the study of the economic growth with the help of this model and the production function of Cobb - Douglas (Solow, 1956) resulted in the fact that this version was called in his honor ‘the Solow model’ (some its modification was called ‘the Solow - Swan model’). In this paper we consider two forecast options of the Polish economy development designed basing on the simplest dynamic model for an open economy. The dynamic model of the economy proposed in (Olenev, Pechenkin, 2007) and used in the paper is called the Ramsey type model, since a great attention in this work is paid to determining the share of accumulation in the economy. In order to make the forecast possible, the problem of identifying the external parameters of the whole model is solved. The identification of the model (Olenev, Pechenkin, 2007) made it possible to determine the reasons for the economic growth in the 2000s in Russia. The growth was caused by the return of the production assets excluded from the production process during the unsuccessful experiments of the 1990s, and involved again after the default of 1998. This interpretation of the identification results allowed to calculate it at the end of 2006 that in 2008 the problems caused by the depletion of the reserve production assets were going to arise in the Russian economy. Unfortunately, the forecast (Olenev, Pechenkin, 2007) was not heard in time, so the relevant measures were not taken in advance. This resulted in the crisis of 2008, which was first explained by the global financial crisis that happened that year. Only ten years later it was officially recognized that the causes of the Russian crisis were internal. Here we consider the problem of building several forecast scenarios that reflect the variants of the future economy dynamics in the most accurate way. We build a basic scenario according to the obtained external parameters of the dynamic Ramsey model for the Polish economy. Using the original numerical-analytical method, we find all the external parameters of the model, including parameters of a homogeneous production function with a constant elasticity of substitution. The method includes the evaluation of the proximity between the model trajectories calculated with the given parameters and their statistical analogs: this means the real historical time series of macroeconomic indicators, such as the gross domestic product (GDP) Y, investment J and other components of the balance of GDP usage. Further a choice of such a set of parameters, for which the compared trajectories are closest to each other basing on the criterion of the Theil inequality, is made. Then we design an optimistic scenario, taking into account the period 2010-2016, which reflects the nowadays trend of labor force in Poland most representatively. We reidentify the parameters of the model, investigate the accuracy of the model basing on the Theil criterion. And finally we calculate the future values of gross domestic product and investments according to both scenarios, make a comparison and visualization, which lets us make an analytical interpretation of the obtained results. Model description In order to describe the Polish economy model, we consider a Ramsey type dynamic model (Olenev, Pechenkin, 2007; Kamenev, Olenev, 2015) of a kind = O[( )/O)-b + (1 )( )/O)-b]-1/b, (1) where Y is gross domestic product, L is amount of people involved in the economy, K is amount of capital involved in the economy. Y0, L0, K0 are initial conditions for the functions Y, L, K at the chosen moment of time (year), given at constant 2010 prices. According to their economic sense, parameters a, b are restricted by the relations a ∈ (0, 1), b > -1. Then, basing on the statistical data (The United Nations Statistics Division, 2018; International Labour Organization, 2018), we make the next assumptions about the labor L and investments J d L = γ , (0) = , (2) d t O d К = () -μ , (0) = , (3) d t O where J is gross capital formation,γ > 0, μ are parameters of the model. Basic model scenario In order to build the basic forecast of the Polish economy development, we consider the time period from 1900 till 2016. Further everywhere in this section it is assumed that t = 0 corresponds to 1990. Then, if the number of the year is denoted as n, the internal time is = 1990. Formula (1) shows that the gross domestic product Y(t) is determined by a homogeneous production function with a constant elasticity of substitution. The initial conditions for the three functions L, K, Y are O = 17.438, O = 635.507η, O = 635.507 (4) and are taken as the values for 1990 from (Solow, 1956) .The values of the function L are given in millions of people, of the functions K, Y - in billions of zlotys. Let us consider the graph of the function stat (Figure 1). The corresponding values from (Solow, 1956) are represented by dots in this graph. By using a leastsquares method to find a fit to a list of data of values stat we obtain the equality () = 17.438 -O.OO1t. (5) Figure 1. Points represent values of and the straight line is defined by the equation (5) Source: own elaboration Functions (), () are connected to each other by the relation ) = cr p(t) ∗ (), (6) where the coefficient cr p(t) is defined from the tables (The United Nations Statistics Division, 2018), σ is the average value of the ratio of investments in a given year at current prices to GDP in the same year at current prices, and p() is equal to pJ(t) ; the numerator of this fraction is the ratio of the investments at current prices pY(t) to its value at constant 2010 prices and the denominator is the same ratio of GDP. The graph of the coefficient cr p(t) appropriately to years is depicted on Figure 2. The corresponding values of the function p() are calculated basing on the statistical data (The United Nations Statistics Division, 2018), and coefficient σ is defined as the average value σav; then we use the least squares method to build a line cr p(t) = 0.179 + 0.002. (7) Taking into account the equality (7), we rewrite the relation (6) in the form () = (0.179 + 0.002) ∗ (). (8) We solve differential equation (3) as a difference equation. Using the Euler method with a time step of 1 year, as well as taking into account the initial conditions (4) and relation (5) we obtain ( + 1) = (1 ) () + (104.402 + 1.476)(O.OOO3b + (1 )6.454b( t))-b)-1⁄b, (9) where 5. Figure 2. Points represent values of , the straight line is defined by the equation (7) () Source: own elaboration. Substituting (4) and (9) into (1), we obtain a recurrence relation for the function Y. Using the method outlined in the paper (Ramsey, 1928), according to the formula ∑n (t t )2 ( ) = 1 ∑n t=1 t 2 n 2 t=1 + ∑t=1 t we build the coefficient of proximity Y for the function Y, and then, considering the formula (7), we build the coefficient of proximity J for the function J. Then we build a closure (Olenev, Pechenkin, 2007) for the product of functions YJ and find its maximum on the following intervals of variation of the parameters (0.1,1), ∈ (0.1,1),μ ∈ (0.01, 0.09),η ∈ (0.1, 1.5). Such intervals are chosen on the basis of economic considerations (Olenev, Pechenkin, 2007). Carrying out the numerical analysis of the values of parameters on the indicated intervals using the method of enumeration with the step of 0.1 for the parameter , with the step of 0.1 for the parameter , with the step of 0.01 for the parameter μ, with the step of 0.1 f or the parameter η, we obtain the set of parameters ( μ, η) = (0.3, 0.3, 0.05, 1.3), (10) under which the product YJ take the value 0.9124. Let us draw graphics for the functions Y and stat (Figure 3) and J and stat (Figure 4). Figure 3. Comparison of calculated Y and statistical values of GDP Source: own elaboration. Figure 4. Comparison of calculated J and statistical values of investment Source: own elaboration. Assuming that the parameters ( μ, η) keep their values for the next 5 years, we make a forecast for 2017-2021. In order to do this, we calculate the values of the functions Y and J for 2017-2021 (Tables 1 and 2). The values of the function Y for 2017-2021 Table 1 Year 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 Yprog 1779.01 1830.23 1881.66 1933.28 1985.05 The values of the function J for 2017-2021 Table 2 Year 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 Yprog 399.695 415.455 431.501 447.828 464.430 In order to show visually how the situation is going to change according to this scenario, we will draw the graphs of the obtained function values of Y and J for 2017-2021 as the continuation of the graphs of the values of these functions for 1991-2016 (Figures 5 and 6) showing the beginning part of the trend. Figure 5. The forecast of GDP dynamics for 2016-2020 according to the first scenario Source: own elaboration. Figure 6. The forecast of investment dynamics for 2016-2020 according to the first scenario Source: own elaboration. Alternative model scenario One of the crucial functions of economic modeling is to present several scenarios of forecasts considering different changes in separate parameters. This function lets the decision-makers observe the situation from different points of view, estimate the alternative costs of each direction that can hypothetically be chosen. In our case, observing the data series of the parameter L (the number of people involved in an economy) on the Figure 1, we can see, that the nowadays trend has its beginning in the twentieth point, which corresponds to the year 2010. The declines in the amount of economically active people can be easily explained, if we take a look at the time period which they belong to. This time period corresponds to the process of Polish integration to EU, which caused the significant outflow of workers from Poland. So, assuming that till 2010 this process has burnt out and the further curve shows us the actual trend of the labor force dynamics, we look for the function to define the function L between the years 2010-2016. In this case, if the number of the year is denoted as n, the internal time is = 2010. In order to make a forecast based on this shorter period, we have to reidentify the model according to the statistical data, related to this period. If we take year 2010 as the starting point, the initial conditions for the three functions L, K, Y are O = 18.036, O = 1445.297η, O = 1445.297 (11) also taken from (The United Nations Statistics Division, 2018; International Labour Organization, 2018), like in the first case. Basing on the statistical data, we build a graphic of the coefficient cr , p(t) which is defined from the tables (The United Nations Statistics Division, 2018), during the 2010-2016 period. Then we find a function, which approximates the obtained curve best. In our case, this function is next cr p(t) = 0.209 + 0.003 0.003 sin . (12) Visually the way this function approximates cr p(t) is shown on the Figure 7. We apply the same method to design the function, approximating the L function. The obtained function is the core of this forecast scenario, and, basing on the statistics (International Labour Organization, 2018), we get the next its form: ℒ() = 17.966 + 0.193 0.049 + 0.0043 0.093 sin . (13) Like in the first case, we solve differential equation (3) as a difference equation. Using the Euler method and taking a time step of 1 year, as well as taking into account the initial conditions (4) and relation (5) we obtain ( 1) = () μ () + (302.226 + 3.983 3.887 sin ) х х ((0.996 + 0.011 0.003 2 + 0.0002 3 0.005 sin )-b + where 5. -b +(1 )7.276 b ( t)) Т 1 ь ), (14) Figure 7. Points represent values of , the straight line is defined by the equation (12) () Source: own elaboration. Substituting (11) and (14) into (1), we obtain a recurrence relation for the function Y. We are using the same method, outlined in the paper (Olenev, Pechenkin, 2007), as it was done in the first case, to build a closure (Olenev, Pechenkin, 2007) for the product of functions YJ and find its maximum on the following intervals of variation of the parameters (0.1,1), ∈ (0.1,1),μ ∈ (0.01, 0.09),η ∈ (0.1, 1.5). Such intervals are chosen on the basis of economic considerations (Olenev, Pechenkin, 2007). Carrying out the numerical analysis of the values of parameters on the indicated intervals using the method of enumeration with the step of 0.05 for the parameter , with the step of 0.05 for the parameter , with the step of 0.005 for the parameter μ, with the step of 0.05 for the parameter η, we obtain the set of parameters ( μ, η) = (0.4, 0.9, 0.09, 1.5), (15) under which the product YJ take the value 0.953553. Let us draw graphics for the functions Y and stat (Figure 8) and J and stat (Figure 9). Assuming that the parameters ( μ, η) keep their values for the next 5 years, we make a forecast for 2017-2021. In order to do this, we calculate the values of the functions Y and J for 2017-2021 (Tables 3 and 4). In order to show visually how the situation is going to change according to this scenario, we will draw the graphs of the obtained function values of Y and J for 2017-2021 as the continuation of the graphs of the values of these functions for 1991-2016 (Figures 10 and 11) showing the beginning part of the trend. Figure 8. Comparison of calculated Y and statistical values of investment according to the second scenario Source: own elaboration. Figure 9. Comparison of calculated J and statistical values of investment according to the second scenario Source: own elaboration. The values of the function Y for 2017-2021 Table 3 Year 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 Yprog 1749.11 1796.26 1852.80 1920.17 1997.20 The values of the function J for 2017-2021 Table 4 Year 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 Yprog 396.408 410.439 431.341 457.255 483.552 Figure 10. The forecast of GDP dynamics for 2016-2020 according to the second scenario Source: own elaboration. Figure 11. The forecast of investments dynamics for 2016-2020 according to the second scenario Source: own elaboration. Conclusion The main results obtained during the study of the paper are next: Identification values of the parameters for the Ramsey type model (1)-(3), got basing on the data of Polish economy of 1991-2016 in the first case and on the same statistics of 2010-2016 in the second one, are different. Their values are next: - first scenario: = 0.3, = 0.3, μ = 0.05, η = 1.3; - second scenario: = 0.4, = 0.9, μ = 0.09, η = 1.5. The forecasted values of gross domestic product and investments show different dynamics. According to the first scenario, where we assume, that the trend of the future economy parameters changes will stay the same during the forecasted period, we get the next results: · forecasted gross domestic product in 2021 - 1997.20 billions of zlotys, average annual increment - 3.37%; · forecasted investments in 2021 - 483.552 billions of zlotys, average annual increment - 0.5%. According to the second scenario, where we assume, that the trend of the future economy parameters changes is conditioned by the changes in labor force during 2010-2016, we get the next results: · forecasted gross domestic product in 2021 - 1985.05 billions of zlotys, average annual increment - 2.78%; · forecasted investments in 2021 - 464.430 billions of zlotys, average annual increment - 3.8%. This leads us to the conclusion, that considering the whole period 1990-2016 when identifying model, we get a higher forecasted value of GDP of year 2021 by 0.6% than considering the period 2010-2016. At the same time, we get a significantly higher rate of the investments growth (0.59 percentage points).

×

About the authors

Valeriya A Chychuryna

European University in Warsaw

Author for correspondence.
Email: takotsubocard@gmail.com

PhD Student

22 Białostocka St., Warsaw, 03-741, Republic of Poland

Nikolay N Olenev

Dorodnicyn Computing Centre, FRC CSC RAS; Peoples’ Friendship University of Russia (RUDN University)

Email: nolenev@mail.ru

Cand. Sc. (Phys. and Math.), Docent, Leading Researcher; Associated Professor, Nikol’skii Mathematical Institute

40 Vavilov St., Moscow, 119333, Russian Federation; 6 Miklukho-Maklaya St., Moscow, 117198, Russian Federation

References

  1. Clements M.P., Hendry D.F. (2002). An Overview of Economic Forecasting. A Companion to Economic Forecasting (Chapter 1). Oxford, Blackwells.
  2. International Labour Organization. (2018, February 13). ILOSTAT database. Retrieved from https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/SL.TLF.TOTL.IN?locations=PL
  3. Joutz F.L. (2006). Econometric Forecasting Models. The Middle Atlantic Actuarial Club. Kamenev G.K., Olenev N.N. (2015). Study of the Russian Economy’s Identification and Forecast
  4. Stability Using a Ramsey Type Model. Mathematical Models and Computer Simulations, (2), 79-189.
  5. Moiseev N.N. (1975). Prostejshie matematicheskie modeli jekonomicheskogo rosta [Simplest mathematical models of economic growth]. Matematika, kibernetika. Moscow. 66 p. (In Russ.)
  6. Olenev N.N. (2015). A study of structural changes influence on Russian economy. Bulletin of Peoples’ Friendship University of Russia. Series: Economics, (1), 150-157.
  7. Olenev N.N., Pechenkin R.V., Chernetsov A.M. (2007). Parallel'noe programmirovanie v MATLAB i ego prilozhenija [Parallel MATLAB programming and its applications]. Moscow, VC RAN Publ. 120 p. (In Russ.)
  8. Ramsey F.P. (1928). A Mathematical Theory of Saving. The Economic Journal, 38(1520), 543-559
  9. Shaw A. (2017). Why economic forecasting has always been a flawed science. The Guardian. Retrieved from https://www.theguardian.com/money/2017/sep/02/economic-forecastingflawed-science-data
  10. Solow R.M. (1956). A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, (1), 65-94
  11. The United Nations Statistics Division. (2018, February 13). National Accounts Main Aggregates Data. Retrieved from https://unstats.un.org/unsd/snaama/dnllist.asp

Copyright (c) 2019 Chychuryna V.A., Olenev N.N.

Creative Commons License
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

This website uses cookies

You consent to our cookies if you continue to use our website.

About Cookies